Of all the unfounded myths that have wrecked our cities over the past 100 years, one stands among the giants. It’s the belief that widening roads eases congestion.
You’ve probably heard people repeat this myth over the years – your in-laws, your neighbors, and perhaps even your mayor. Indeed, recently I personally witnessed the mayors of both Austin and San Francisco, under pressure from congestion-addled residents, say exactly this.
They’re all wrong. We’ve had the evidence for a century and cities have proceeded as if they didn’t know. In the process, much that’s good about cities – their charm, strong communities, convenience, safety, economic stability – has been eroded. It would be no exaggeration to say that much of what separates great and poor cities depends on how they’ve handled congestion.
What follows is the evidence for why road-widening doesn’t work as a congestion-reliever, what road-widening actually achieves, and how congestion should really be addressed. Read it, forward it, and don’t let anybody get away with pushing road widening as a congestion solution.
Congestion sucks but not as much as you might think
Congestion is hell. According to a Hewlett-Packard study, cited in the 2013 book Happy City, people snarled in traffic suffer worse stress than fighter pilots and riot police on the job. (Just don’t take that as a recommendation to become a fighter pilot or a riot cop to avoid your commute.)
We all hate congestion. But how much of a problem is it objectively? Not as much as you might think…
To many, congestion is one of society’s great evils. This is not the case. Even the upper estimates of congestion costs show them to be minor compared to vehicle ownership, parking costs, and air pollution impacts. Congestion isn’t a major problem and certainly shouldn’t be addressed ahead of other more damaging costs. In fact, congestion tends to increase in cities with higher GDP per capita. It’s actually a sign of success!
Widening roads only worsens congestion
For many people, including state highway department employees (aka foxes guarding the sheep), road widening is the magic pill to ease congestion. In fact, widening roads to reduce congestion is worse than doing nothing.

The Katy Freeway, Houston. Credit: Chron.
One might assume that a wider road allows traffic to flow more smoothly by allocating the same number of vehicles more space. This argument contains a fatal flaw: When roads get wider more people start driving, a phenomenon known as “induced demand”. People drive when they used to bike, walk, or take public transit; they move farther away from their jobs in town and drive farther to get there; they drive in rush hour when they used to drive at other times; and businesses that depend more on roads will relocate to cities, bringing more truck traffic with them.
(The common claim that getting more people onto bikes or into buses will take more cars off the roads and ease congestion is also bogus. Induced demand means that for every person that switches from driving to an alternative, another driver will take their place. Certainly, alternatives to driving should be encouraged for many reasons, but congestion relief shouldn’t be one of them.)
Houston’s Katy Freeway stands as only the most extreme in a long line of road widening horror stories. In 2008 Texas pumped over $2.8 billion into widening Katy to 23 lanes, making it the world’s widest freeway. The result? From 2011-2014 the morning commute time rose by 30% and the evening commute by 55%. (And you’d never believe what’s now being proposed…)
Are the new drivers’ lives significantly better? It’s unlikely. Most of this extra traffic, because it’s of the kind that’s easily given up when congestion gets bad, is considered of marginal value. And the extra costs of collisions, vehicle ownership, air pollution, and other costs (see the chart above) eat further into the dubious benefits of all those new drivers.
Narrowing or removing roads eases congestion
If widening roads worsens congestion then is it also true that narrowing or removing roads reduces congestion? Yes. A 1998 study of 60 cases worldwide showed that when a road is closed or its capacity reduced an average of 20% of traffic disappears. The study found instances where 60% of the traffic disappeared. It isn’t displaced to other roads, it simply vanishes. We’re back to those marginal value rides again. There’s great flexibility in people’s trips and it’s relatively easy for them to avoid making the trip, change its timing, or ride another way.
This is a crucial piece of evidence to support what should be a priority for towns and cities everywhere: Creating public space – car-free and in the center of town. Even if this public space occupies former auto-oriented streets (usually the best candidates for public space), there’s unlikely to be much overflow to neighboring streets.

A beautiful place for people. Quincy Market, Boston MA. Credit: Boston Geology.
Road widening is bad economics
State departments of transportation (DOTs) – often jokingly called highway departments (which is what some of them actually used to be called) – seek out road-building projects as a way to keep their personnel in work.
This might be good for highway builders but it’s bad for the economy overall. A 2010 study concludes that bicycle and pedestrian infrastructure creation (a drop in the bucket of all state DOT expenses) generates up to double the number of jobs compared to automobile infrastructure. For every $1,000,000 spent on gasoline only about 5 jobs are generated (and this is a generous estimate).
And the aftermath of road-widening is an even more automobile-oriented society, which weakens local economies. Most auto-related spending leaves the local economy, auto-infrastructure prevents land from generating property taxes, and tourists tend to avoid car-oriented places.
The lesson is simple: Road widening is bad economics.
How to actually move people more quickly
We’ve established that widening roads is not an effective way of reduce commute times. So what is? The answer is the “multimodal street”, a fancy way of saying a street designed for not only cars but for walking (sidewalks), bicycling (protected bike lanes), and public transportation (bus-only lanes).
Let’s compare the capacity of a car-oriented street with a multimodal street:

Source: NACTO Global Street Design Guide
The evidence is that streets with bike lanes, bus-only lanes, wide sidewalks, and (if they must be there) car lanes carry over twice as many people per hour and thus decrease travel times as streets designed for just cars. This is because biking, busing, and walking consume much less space per person and encourage more compact development, reducing traveling distances.
Go Sing It On The Mountain
No longer can road widening be justified as a congestion-easing tool. Road widening lengthens commutes, increases household costs, worsens pollution, harms the economy, and, let us not forget, kills and injures millions of people globally every year. Transportation departments and politicians had the evidence decades ago and many continue to ignore it to this day. We need to make them understand.
The solution to congestion is compact development and multimodal (and sometimes pedestrian-only) streets. Wherever cars come into contact with well-designed human-scaled cities there’ll always be congestion; cars are extremely inefficient uses of space, after all, and are incompatible with great places. The question is: Do we want a lot of traffic congestion or a little?
And remember: Not all types of congestion are bad…
The charts used in this article are part of Victoria Transport Policy Institute‘s Todd Litman’s excellent presentation “Economics of Highway Spending and Traffic Congestion“, a highly recommended read.
Increasing capacity on roads is a good thing. Period. Article doesn’t represents pros and cons, just cons.
It twists statistics.(Katy freeway study needs to compare average speed before and after expansion, not average commute time. People may not be driving further)
One thing everyone can agree on…
Fewer lanes reduces traffic.
In other words, getting in your car and driving is such a shitty ordeal with insufficient road capacity, that people would prefer to stay home then go to dinner, movies, etc.
They’d prefer to take a shitty job nearby then a good job further away.
What “Good things”…exactly? Let’s see..asthma, death, injuries, dependence on commuting, the land that was taken will be forever non-productive, the land around it will be lower value…
And the list goes on.
I vigorously supporting great walkability for projects nationwide. However, we need to be technically correct as we proceed. The capacity analysis offered in the article is only valid for a limited percentage of land area in existing and proposed US cities. Buildings of substantial size, likely over five stories, placed on small blocks of 600 feet maximum, are required to generate the travel demand sufficient to load buses to capacity twice a minute. Sidewalk movements of 16,000 per hour require buildings of similar five plus height and compactness within a square miles, so individuals would walk in those great numbers. in SmartCode terms, T5 Urban Center and T6 Urban Core development patterns are required for this level of transit and pedestrian travel. The six lane arterial, by comparison, in the same T5 and T6 context would also generate 16,000 pedestrians and could fill many transit busses, if available. Therefore, the question is how many square miles of T5 and T6 can we expect in the near future. Chris Leinberger says Walkable Urban, or WalkUPs, in Atlanta occupy 0.55% of the Metro Atlanta area and existing and emerging WalkUPs will use 0.88 percent of the region’s land mass. If the capacity comparison is made within this specifically defined context then the highly multimodal, complete street could approach the stated capacity. The bottom line, all the transportation and land use pattern discussion is context based and should be emphasized as such.
Keep up the enthusiasm and the good work and we will see change.
Rick Hall P.E.
Nice article and fully agreed. Being an urban designer, we have also been advocating pedestrian friendly cities here in the historic towns of the Kathmandu valley, but the concerned authorities see road widening as the only solution for ever growing traffic congestion. Without regulating urban density, land use and mobility behaviour, widening of roads in the Kathmandu valley has creating more traffic congestion thereby causing air pollution.
Like motorcycles and bicycles, cars best designed single-width to maximize the ability to move through traffic. These types of cars include the iRoad from Toyota, the Land Glider from Nissan, and the Tango from Commuter Cars. They’re all electric, and the Tango is highway capable.
Imagine if all pedaled vehicles had side by side seating like the novelty quadricycles you can see in amusement areas. Bike paths would have to be widened in order to get the single occupant riders more width to go to their jobs.
Narrow the cars to widen the roads.
You are focusing only on the form of the car. You leave out that anyone in a car can create death with ease and just a splash of carelessness. Making the cars more narrow…just makes them more efficient killers.
How many cars were actually on streets that had been widened to handle between 30,000 and 50,000 vehicles per day?
You mentioned several times that there’s ONLY one solution. That’s a bit arrogant, no? Why does widening highways induce demand? Probably because people value being able to use that highway far greater than it costs to use it (most highways in the US are free to use). Changing the economics of that equation could drastically change each individual’s value calculation. Were highways tolled or congested areas priced (as downtown and midtown Manhattan now will be), average travel times would decrease and congestion would ease, without changing space on streets.
Adding biking, walking, and public transportation infrastructure are clear no-brainers. They make much more livable spaces and provide far more transportation capacity than one person per vehicle travel lanes. But, at the beginning of your article, you claim that moving commuters to public transportation makes no impact on congestion (it induces demand with the road space that former driver used to use now freed up), while at the end you argue that public transportation adds far more capacity to roads.